Carbon taxes do not harm jobs or economic growth

Results from two recent analyses suggest that implementing carbon taxes has no discernible detrimental effects on employment and GDP growth.

This article has been reprinted with minor changes and permission from RFF’s Resources Magazine.
Written by Gilbert Metcalf and James Stock

Economists broadly agree that placing a price on carbon, whether through a cap-and-trade program or a tax, is a key element of an economically efficient suite of policies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. In the current US Congress, numerous bills propose the establishment of national carbon tax systems, along with a few that push for cap-and-trade programs. These bills reflect a growing consensus that action is needed at the national level to curb carbon pollution in the United States and that a carbon tax is the most straightforward way to do that. The bills also reflect the existing consensus among economists, as typified by the more than 3,500 economists (including us) who signed the Climate Leadership Council’s statement published in the Wall Street Journal last year, which calls for a carbon tax as “the most cost-effective lever to reduce carbon emissions at the scale and speed that is necessary.”

However, a major stumbling block to pricing carbon pollution is concern over the macroeconomic impacts of the policy. The Trump administration’s retreat from national climate policy reflects a belief that ambitious climate action could have detrimental consequences for economic growth and employment. While initiating a process to withdraw the United States from the global Paris Agreement, for example, the president claimed that the cost to the economy would be “close to $3 trillion in lost GDP and 6.5 million industrial jobs.”

How should we assess the economic costs of a carbon tax? Until recently, most analyses have been based on large-scale computable general equilibrium models. One of these models, the Goulder-Hafstead E3 model, is the engine behind one of Resources for the Future’s digital data tools, the Carbon Pricing Calculator. Today, we have enough experience with carbon tax systems around the world to carry out statistical analyses of existing carbon taxes: with the first one implemented in 1990, we can draw from up to three decades of data. 

Directly examining the empirical evidence has two virtues. First, estimating the real-world effects of carbon taxes on GDP, employment, and emissions reductions speaks directly to concerns that they kill jobs. Second, the empirical estimates provide a check on the calibrated theoretical models.

In two recent papers, we carry out an analysis of the 31 countries that comprise the European Union–wide emissions trading system (EU-ETS). While all of these countries price a portion of their emissions through this cap-and-trade system, 15 of the countries also impose a carbon tax, mostly on emissions not covered by the EU-ETS. By limiting our analysis to countries that are part of the EU-ETS, we can identify the incremental impact of carbon taxes on economic output, employment, and emissions by leveraging the variation in carbon tax systems within this group of nations.

For a wide range of specifications, we find no evidence of adverse effects on GDP growth or total employment. We also find that long-run growth rates of GDP and employment are unaffected by the tax. This latter finding is consistent with macroeconomic theory, which suggests that long-run growth rates are driven by fundamentals such as technological progress, which in turn are unaffected by changes in relative prices. Our results also are consistent with most general equilibrium modeling of climate policy. Finally, we find cumulative emissions reductions on the order of 4 to 6 percent for a tax of $40 per ton of CO2 covering 30 percent of emissions. We argue that this is likely to be a lower bound on reductions for a broad-based carbon tax in the United States because European ones do not include in their tax base the power sector, which has the lowest marginal cost of carbon pollution abatement. (In Europe, power sector carbon emissions are priced under the EU-ETS.)

european union 
Table 1 shows the considerable variation in European carbon taxes in terms of their tax rates, coverage, and time of enactment. Figure 1 shows annual GDP growth rates before and after the implementation of a carbon tax in the individual countries. While the point estimate of the average GDP growth across countries that enacted a carbon tax suggests a modest increase in the growth rate, there is wide variation and—more importantly—no evidence of the tax hurting economic growth. Figure 1 is only suggestive, because it does not control for other factors that might influence growth or relate to a carbon tax, nor does it allow for the possibility that countries with existing strong GDP growth might feel confident enough to adopt a carbon tax. But in our recent papers, we address these econometric problems and estimate the causal effect of a carbon tax on GDP, employment, and emissions.

carbon taxes and gdp growth
GDP growth before and after the imposition of a carbon tax among European countries covered by the EU Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS). Gray lines represent 15 countries; red points indicate the average among countries, with associated confidence intervals; horizontal lines indicate the pre/post means.

 
Identifying the dynamic causal effect of a carbon tax on GDP growth is complicated by the possibility of what is called “simultaneity”: poor economic outcomes could lead tax authorities to reduce the rate or to postpone a planned increase. Our approach is based on the insight that changes to a carbon tax can be thought of as having two components: one that responds to historical economic growth, and another that’s unrelated to past growth. The latter category can include tax changes based on legal mandates that follow a preordained schedule, changes in ambition based on the environmental preferences of the party in power, or responses to international pressure on climate policy. We argue that this latter category of changes—those not predicted by historical GDP growth or current and past international economic shocks—are exogenous. This assumption allows us to estimate the dynamic effect on GDP growth from the unexpected component of a carbon tax using a vector autoregressive framework.

We report results by simulating a one-time permanent increase of $40 in a carbon tax that covers 30 percent of the country’s emissions (a coverage rate close to the sample mean) and constructing impulse response functions. Figure 2 shows a typical impulse response function for GDP growth rates.

carbon tax and gdp growth
A typical impulse response function for the annual rate of growth of GDP in response to a permanent $40 increase in a carbon tax, estimated using a structural vector autoregression. The red line indicates the point estimate, and the two shaded areas indicate 67 percent and 95 percent confidence bands.

 
Three things stand out. First, the point estimate is positive, but small. Second, we cannot reject the possibility that the carbon tax has no effect on GDP growth. And third, we can reject the possibility that the carbon tax exerts an economically significant negative impact on GDP. These findings are consistent across our analyses: we find similar results for total employment growth rates (Figure 3) and manufacturing employment.

carbon tax and total employment growth
A typical impulse response function for annual rate of growth of employment in response to a permanent $40 increase in a carbon tax, estimated using a structural vector autoregression. The red line indicates the point estimate, and the two shaded areas indicate 67 percent and 95 percent confidence bands.
emissions in response to carbon tax
A typical impulse response function for the percentage reduction in carbon emissions in response to a permanent $40 increase in a carbon tax, estimated using a structural vector autoregression. The red line indicates the point estimate, and the two shaded areas indicate 67 percent and 95 percent confidence bands.

 
Finally, we estimate the impact of this $40 tax on cumulative carbon dioxide emissions. We find a point estimate of a 6.5 percent decline in emissions (Figure 4), though the error bands are wide. While we cannot reject the possibility that the carbon tax has zero impact in most years, we also cannot reject the possibility of double-digit declines in emissions. Worth noting is that countries applying a broad-based carbon tax should view these simulated reductions as lower bounds on potential emissions reductions, since the EU-ETS cap-and-trade system already covers those sectors where emissions reductions are least costly to implement, and so those sectors are generally not subject to the carbon tax.

 

Share

Interview

COP28 | MASSIMO TAVONI. “Science points to a loss and damage fund of several hundred billion USD”

The loss and damage fund has been established, and initial pledges have been made, but how much money should be directed into it and how should it be organized? Massimo Tavoni, director of the CMCC-RFF European Institute on Economics and the Environment, explains how climate-economic science and modeling can support the loss and damage debate. The latest evidence indicates that an adequate fund should be in the order of [140-822] USD billion and that it should differ from existing funding arrangements used for mitigation and adaptation.

Article

Current concentrations of CO2 last experienced 3-5 million years ago

Levels of the atmospheric greenhouse gases (GHGs) carbon dioxide (CO2), methane (CH4), and nitrous oxide (N2O) have all reached new highs in 2017, according to …

Interview

Information saves lives

Accurate, timely, and reliable: the availability and management of information in an emergency are crucial to reduce damages and improve recovery efforts. With Chiara Menchise, United Nations Office for Disaster Risk Reduction, we explore the world of information technologies applied to disaster risk reduction, including social media, remote sensing, satellite imageries and Artificial Intelligence.